Skip to main content
  • Letter to Editor
  • Open access
  • Published:

Comment on “binge drinking and alcohol prices”

A Letter to the Editor to this article was published on 02 February 2016

The Original Article was published on 12 February 2015

To the editors of health economics review:

There is ample evidence on the effects of prices and taxes on heavy drinking, including binge drinking [1]. Experiments on “Happy Hour” discounts in barroom settings have shown that when the price of alcohol decreases, consumption increases, and vice versa [2, 3]. A well-cited meta-analysis of 112 studies (Wagenaar et al., [4]) identified ten studies on heavy drinking and estimated a significant elasticity of −0.28. Another systematic review by Elder and colleagues [5] concluded that alcohol tax levels were inversely associated with excessive drinking. This is consistent with the conclusion from a widely-cited review by Cook and Moore [6] that “an increase in price results in reduced consumption”, and this applies to drinking by youth, heavy drinkers, and alcoholics who develop cirrhosis due to chronic consumption. Xuan and colleagues [7] showed that an improved comprehensive measure of alcohol taxes including specific excise tax and value-based taxes resulted in more negative tax elasticity and price elasticity predicting binge drinking, as compared to a conventional measure that relies only on beer excise tax. Another meta-analysis by Wagenaar and colleagues [8] showed that increased taxes and prices were associated with reduced alcohol-related disease and injury outcomes that are attributable to binge drinking.

Nevertheless, in an issue of Health Economics Review, Dr. Jon Nelson published a “systematic” review article with the following conclusion: “Increased alcohol taxes or prices are unlikely to be effective as a means to reduce binge drinking, regardless of gender or age group.” [9]. We have reviewed this paper based on its methodology, study interpretation, and conclusion.

Faulty methodology

There is a general consensus that the scientifically recommended approach to estimate an overall effect across multiple studies is meta-analysis. Meta-analysis is the final step in the standardized protocol detailed in Preferred Reporting Items for Systematic Reviews and Meta-Analyses (PRISMA), which was cited in the Nelson paper. However, instead of conducting a rigorous meta-analysis among the 56 studies that he manually selected and screened, Dr. Nelson deviated from the PRISMA approach by simply counting the number of studies with p ≤ 0.05. Dr. Nelson’s approach failed to account for the heterogeneity of the effect sizes and sample variation due to different studies, and potential publication bias. Dr. Nelson stated that due to “diversity of models and results,” quantitative coefficient estimates for a meta-analysis were not collected. Dr. Nelson’s reference to “diversity of models and results” is the exact reason why quantitative meta-analysis is necessary to obtain a common effect estimate in the first place.

Furthermore, among the exclusion criteria, Dr. Nelson stated that studies were excluded if they are “based on a laboratory experiment” or use an interrupted time-series analysis. He did not explain why these two research designs were excluded. Not only do they have better internal validity than other designs, interrupted time series analysis is an ideal method for evaluating natural experiments, a type of study included in Dr. Nelson’s paper and stated in the article title.

Misconstrued interpretations

Based on his characterization of our own work, there is considerable evidence of misconstrued presentation of the literature in Dr. Nelson’s article. For example, Dr. Nelson cited a study by Xuan et al. [10] and stated “Not signif. w/ adult binge incl.” in Table 2 in Dr. Nelson’s article. This representation of the study finding is incorrect. Xuan et al. [10] found that a higher beer tax was associated with significantly lower odds of youth binge drinking among the participants of biennial Youth Risk Behavior Surveys from 1999 to 2009, and the effect of alcohol taxes on reduced youth binge drinking was mediated (explained) in part through its effect on reducing adult binge drinking. In other words, adult binge drinking was being assessed as a possible mediator on the causal pathway between alcohol tax and youth binge drinking, and was not a covariate. Journal readers, based on Dr. Nelson’s statement of non-significance, were therefore erroneously informed that this study did not find a significant inverse relationship between tax and youth binge drinking when the opposite was the case.

Dr. Nelson further asserted that evidence in several widely-cited studies is drawn from aggregate econometric studies, and here he cited another one of our studies (Nelson TF et al., [11]). His assertion was incorrect because this study was based on ratings of the efficacy of various alcohol policies. This study was clearly not an econometric study per se, nor were the policy efficacy rating data drawn from econometric studies.

Inadequate literature review

Dr. Nelson subsequently stated that “price and tax elasticity estimates for general populations may not apply equally to binge drinkers and other excessive drinkers.” To support this statement, Dr. Nelson cited Ayyagari and colleagues [12], which was a study restricted to individuals 50 years of age and older. Given the fact that binge drinking prevalence is highest among young adults, the paper cited by Dr. Nelson offers little support for his claim. He further cited a book chapter by Cook and Moore [13] without considering later work by Cook and Moore [6], as cited in the introduction of this letter. Equal effects are not necessary for establishing the critical importance of taxes in reducing excessive consumption and related harms. A more recent study showed that higher alcohol taxes including specific excise tax and value-based taxes were significantly associated with reduced binge drinking among the adult population in United States [7].

Conflict of interest

Dr. Nelson disclosed that “Research leading to this paper was supported in part by the International Center for Alcohol Policies, Washington, DC.” However, the author failed to disclose his role as a consultant (2012–2015) and member of the Research Advisory Board of ICAP, an alcohol industry-funded “social aspect organization”. ICAP-sponsored research has been criticized for faulty methodology and erroneous interpretations [14]. Nor does Dr. Nelson declare that he has received consulting fees from several law firms that represent companies in the alcohol industry on issues related to this paper.

Summary

In summary, Dr. Nelson’s conclusion that taxes were unlikely to be effective at reducing binge drinking is based on faulty methodology and an incorrect interpretation of the findings from studies, and his conclusion contradicts the extensive scientific literature. Binge drinking causes more than half of nearly 80,000 alcohol-attributable deaths in the U.S. each year and accounts for three-quarters of the 224 billion dollars in annual economic costs [15]. This is not a trivial public health issue. Alcohol taxation has been one of the few policy levers that can have substantial benefits on population health. To cast doubt on a near-consensus in the alcohol literature using faulty reasoning and inappropriate review methods does a disservice to science as well as public health.

References

  1. Babor T, Caetano R, Casswell S, Edeards G, Giesbrecht N, Graham K, et al. Alcohol: No Ordinary Commodity – Research and Public Policy. 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2010.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  2. Babor TF, Mendelson JH, Greenberg I, Kuehnle JC. Experimental analysis of the “happy hour:” Effects of purchase price on alcohol consumption. Psychopharmacology. 1978;58:35–41.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  3. Babor TF, Mendelson JH, Uhly B, Souza E. Drinking patterns in experimental and barroom settings. J Stud Alcohol. 1980;41:635–51.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  4. Wagenaar AC, Salois MJ, Komro KA. Effects of beverage alcohol price and tax levels on drinking: a meta-analysis of 1003 estimates from 112 studies. Addiction. 2009;104(2):179–90.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  5. Elder RW, Lawerence B, Ferguson A, Naimi TS, Brewer RD, Chattopadhyay SK, et al. The effectiveness of tax policy interventions for reducing excessive alcohol consumption related harms. Am J Prev Med. 2010;38:217–29.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  6. Cook PJ, Moore MJ. The economics of alcohol abuse and alcohol-control policies. Health Aff. 2002;21(2):120–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Xuan Z, Chaloupka FJ, Blanchette JG, Nguyen TH, Heeren TC, Nelson TF, et al. The relationship between alcohol taxes and binge drinking: evaluating new tax measures incorporating multiple tax and beverage types. Addiction. 2015;110(3):441–50.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  8. Wagenaar AC, Tobler AL, Komro KA. Effects of alcohol tax and price policies on morbidity and mortality: a systematic review. Am J Public Health. 2010;100(11):2270–8.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  9. Nelson JP. Binge drinking and alcohol prices: a systematic review of age-related results from econometric studies, natural experiments and field studies. Heal Econ Rev. 2015;5:6. doi:10.1186/s13561-014-0040-4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Xuan Z, Nelson TF, Heeren T, Blanchette J, Nelson DE, Gruenewald P, et al. Tax policy, adult binge drinking, and youth alcohol consumption in the United States. Alcohol Clin Exp Res. 2013;37(10):1713–9.

    PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  11. Nelson TF, Xuan Z, Babor TF, Brewer RD, Chaloupka FJ, Gruenewald PJ, et al. Efficacy and the strength of evidence of U.S. alcohol control policies. Am J Prev Med. 2013;45(1):19–28.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  12. Ayyagari P, Deb P, Fletcher J, Gallo W, Sindelar JL. Understanding heterogeneity in price elasticities in the demand for alcohol for older individuals. Health Econ. 2013;22:89–105.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  13. Cook PJ, Moore MJ. Alcohol. In: Culyer AJ, Newhouse JP, editors. Handbook of Health Economics, vol. 1B. Amsterdam: Elsevier; 2000. p. 1629–73.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Babor TF, Xuan Z. Alcohol policy research and the grey literature: A tale of two surveys. Nordic Stud Alcohol Drugs. 2004;21:96–107.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Bouchery EE, Harwood HJ, Sacks JJ, Simon CJ, Brewer RD. Economic costs of excessive alcohol consumption in the United States, 2006. Am J Prev Med. 2011;41:516–24.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ziming Xuan.

Additional information

Competing interests

Drs. Xuan and Naimi are supported by research funding from US National Institutes of Health R01AA023376.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Xuan, Z., Babor, T.F., Naimi, T.S. et al. Comment on “binge drinking and alcohol prices”. Health Econ Rev 6, 4 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13561-016-0082-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13561-016-0082-x

Keywords