Skip to main content

Economic evaluation of process utility: elucidating preferences for a non-invasive procedure to treat restenosis

Abstract

Background

In health economic evaluation, utility associated with a health state is outcome-oriented and usually measured using the QALY methodology. Even though there is consistent evidence of utility not only being derived from outcomes but also from procedures, process utility has not been fully integrated in QALY calculations. The aim of this paper is twofold: first, to provide evidence of process utility associated with an alternative treatment to angioplasty, and second, to estimate a monetary value of such process utility using the willingness to pay (WTP) approach.

Methods

A total of 1514 people were polled on their WTP to avoid angioplasty to have a drug-eluting stent (DES) implanted. WTP is estimated with a contingent valuation (CV) survey. Individuals are also asked if they would be WTP for a non-invasive procedure with similar results being achieved. WTP responses were analyzed using a double bounded (DB) logit model.

Results

Most of the participants showed positive preferences for avoiding angioplasty, with an estimated mean WTP of €5692.87. Using QALY gains for avoiding angioplasty, varying from 0.0035 to 0.08 QALYs, our WTP estimate imply monetary values per QALY that range from €71,160.87 to €1,626,534.28.

Discussion

A WTP of €5692.87 to avoid angioplasty imply a monetary value per QALY that greatly exceed the cost per QALY thresholds established in different countries to consider health programs as beneficial to society. Our results reflect how different methodologies for HTA may lead to different conclusions. From the ICER perspective, the cost that would make the treatment with pills option cost-effective, using a threshold of €40,000/QALY, would be €224. However, a cost-benefit approach could support health programs even with a higher cost.

Conclusion

WTP methodology captures outcome and process factors related to angioplasty as our WTP estimations are non-significantly different for the costs of angioplasty. WTP approach must be considered as a genuine alternative to QALY approaches to value process utility.

Background

Utility associated with a health state is often measured in quality-adjusted life years (QALYs).

The QALY approach is considered a consequentialist approach in the sense that use value estimations focus on a final outcome of health gain consequent to health care [1]. Utility associated with a health state is considered to be dependent mainly on outcomes such as duration and severity of a health state [2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9], and measured in the interval [0, 1], where one represents full health and zero a state equivalent to death. The QALYs for each health state is then computed multiplying its utility weight by its duration. The gain in QALYs from avoiding an impaired health state is obtained as the difference between QALYs for full health (HF) and QALYs for that health state (HI).

Therefore, it is assumed that health care has no positive value in use and ignores the possibility of having a negative value in use. In case of restenosis, the primary treatment is an intervention to implant a Drug Eluting Stent (DES). However, let us hypothesize with an alternative treatment with pills that would avoid the intervention. There is no pleasantness in any intervention to cure restenosis, all have negative values in use but, to some extent, there might be preferences for one choice over the other. Other things being equal, restenosis is treated in both cases, given a choice with two options individuals value other aspects of procedures and may have preferences for the non-invasive procedure, as in [10,11,12,13]. These attributes in process of health care enter the utility function [14, 15], have quality of life implications for the individual [16] and can be incorporated into estimates of QALY calculations [17, 18]. The theoretical background for process utility entering the QALY estimations was first introduced by Gerard and Mooney (1993) [15].

Health outcomes are not the only form of benefit in health care since avoiding discomfort or a sense of fear could affect mental health. Considering process utility as a health gain value would lead to optimal provision of health care. Including process utility as an integral part of Health Technology Assessments (HTAs) would strengthen informative tools for decision makers.

Yet, it is difficult to include process utility values when measuring QALYs. Traditional methods to determine health state utility values (such as standard gamble or time trade-off) might not be efficient in the evaluation of process utility. Since these methods trade health attributes against risk of death or against years of life in full health, the amount of risk one would accept or the amount of time given up for process benefits such as treatment administration [19], testing strategies [16] or caregiver characteristics [20] lead to very low gains in QALYs.

In these cases, in a potential economic evaluation using an incremental cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER), a very low gain in QALYs will need to be offset by a very low cost for a treatment or a test to achieve a cost per QALY lower than the socially accepted cost per QALY. It is, therefore, opportune to analyze alternatives for process utility evaluation that might be incorporated in the evaluation of treatments, screening tests, diagnostic tests or therapies that might end up being underestimated if valuation is obtained with traditional health evaluation methods [20, 21].

The aim of this paper is to explore an alternative for process utility evaluation estimating a monetary value. First, to measure whether process utility exists the study includes a comparison of two treatments for restenosis with identical outcomes and different processes. These treatments for restenosis are A) an angioplasty to implant a Drug-Eluting Stent (DES), and B) a hypothetical treatment with pills. We expect respondents to prefer treatment B over treatment A.

Secondly, WTP is estimated using a contingent valuation (CV) tool. Individuals are asked if they would be willing to pay for a treatment with pills as a substitute for angioplasty, with similar health outcomes being achieved. Our research emphasizes the suitability of WTP as an alternative method to value process utility. Monetary evaluation provides a unique value that incorporates the utility/disutility of perceptions and opportunity costs.

The section here-below describes the sample, the questionnaire and the model used to estimate the mean WTP for the treatment with pills. Section 3 contains the model estimates. Section 4 includes a simulated cost-efficiency and cost-benefit analysis for the treatment with pills option and some concluding observations.

Methods

To obtain the monetary value of avoiding angioplasty, a CV survey was designed and presented to 1663 individuals. The interviews were conducted at the respondent’s house, using a Computer Assisted Personal Interview (CAPI) methodology, in February–April 2009. The sampling universe was a population resident in Spain of over 19 year old. The survey sample was stratified in seven categories according to habitat size: less than 2000; 2001–10,000; 10,001-50,000; 50,001–100,000; 100,001-400,000; 400,001-1,000,000, more than 1,000,000 residents. The primary sampling units were 108 municipalities representative of the 17 Spanish regions and the secondary sampling units were houses selected along random routes. In-house selection was according to proportions based on gender and age. Respondents voluntarily participated in the survey. Sample population is representative of the Spanish population; socio-demographic characteristics of sample and Spanish populations are shown in Table 1.

Table 1 Sample Socioeconomic Characteristics

Survey design

The questionnaire was designed to minimise any possible bias or inconsistencies in the responses. A double bounded dichotomous choice format was chosen because, although the NOAA panel report on CV (1993) [22] recommended the use of single bounded dichotomous choice as the only possibility of an “incentive-compatible choice”, a double bounded with a follow up question provides statistical efficiency and more precise welfare estimates [23]. Also, Bateman et al (2008) [24] introduced a Learning Design Contingent Valuation which assumed that repetition and experience in the valuation exercise reduce internal inconsistencies between the first and follow-up question. As choices are repeated and respondents gain familiarity with the decision environment, decisions become less random and more statistically efficient [25]. The questionnaire design also aimed at addressing coherent arbitrariness [26], starting point bias [27, 28] or sequential effects [29]. The questionnaire included an initial evaluation task with two different sequences and four double bound questions on WTP to reduce the risk of restenosis, and a second evaluation task with one double bound question on WTP to avoid restenosis. Finally, respondents answered a number of questions regarding their income, whether they have taken into account that they would have to pay for this, that they could not use that money to pay anything else, if they have the money they have accepted to pay and how would they obtain the money if they did not have it at that moment.

The aim of the questionnaire is twofold; first, it focuses on collecting data to obtain preferences for the DES and second, on obtaining data to elucidate preferences for a treatment with pills The second section of this questionnaire is analyzed here. The analysis of responses in the first section of the questionnaire provided evidence on respondents´ evaluation of the primary treatment of restenosis, DES, and on potential responses biases, such as scope effects [30], which would strengthen the validity of our results and overcome limitations of the WTP design [31].

Initially the participants are informed of the objectives and nature of the study. The interviewer provides information on the causes and symptoms of coronary artery occlusion and how it is usually addressed by the patient undergoing angioplasty to have a stent implanted. The angioplasty procedure is explained in detail and described as minimally invasive and the participants are informed that patients can usually walk unaided after about six hours, leave the hospital within 24 h and be fully recovered within a week. After the evaluation task on willingness to pay for a drug-eluting stent (DES), the questionnaire focuses on the evaluation task for avoiding angioplasty:

As has already been explained, when a fat plaque forms in the coronary artery, it can trigger a heart attack and the usual procedure is angioplasty. This procedure is not complicated, it does not require general anesthesia and patients are usually released from the hospital that very same day. However, patients need two or three days to recover and entering an operating theater is associated with discomfort.

Assume now that an alternative treatment is available, one that is equally effective as a Drug Eluting Stent and does not require surgery—namely, a treatment with pills option that would prevent one from needing to undergo surgery.

The interviewer explains that health outcomes, i.e., the reduction in the probability of restenosis, with the treatment with pills option and with angioplasty is the same. The only benefit of the treatment with pills option compared to a stent is avoidance of the angioplasty required to implant it.

For example:

  • If one opts for the Drug Eluting Stent, the risk of repeated revascularization is 10% (10 cases out of 100).

  • If one opts for the treatment with pills option, the risk of repeated revascularization is 10% (10 cases out of 100); as effective as a DES without one having to suffer the discomfort associated with surgery.

The participants are then asked if they fully understand the process and whether they have any questions. The interviewer repeats the information if necessary.

The participants then respond to a set of questions on their WTP for the treatment with pills option and for avoiding angioplasty. An initial question identifies the individual preferences for the treatment with pills option:

If you have to choose between undergoing surgery to have a DES implanted or being treated with pills, assuming both options are equally effective, which would you choose?

Option A. Treatment with pills

1

Option B. Surgery

2 Give reasons for opting for surgery

Cost information is not provided at this point of the survey and the choice is made taking only the benefit of avoiding the operation into consideration. Individuals choosing the surgery option do not continue with WTP questionnaire after this point and are not included in the WTP calculation. Instead, they were posed a question on the reasons for their preference of the traditional (DES) versus a non –invasive treatment. Those who preferred the treatment with pills option were then asked to provide information on their WTP:

Assume now that you live in a country where Drug Eluting Stents are covered by the Social Security System (DES are free) but that there are some costs you have to pay associated with the treatment with pills option.

Please, look at the following amounts and tell us if you think you would or would not pay that amount. In this case, would you pay for treatment that avoids the need for surgery and is as efficient as a Drug Eluting Stent? To answer, please look at these amounts and indicate whether or not you would pay them:

Option A. I would avoid surgery, choose the treatment with pills option, and pay X€

Option B. I would opt for the Drug Eluting Stent and wouldn’t pay for the treatment with pills option

The evaluation task consists of a choice scenario with an amount (referred to herein as “bid”) and three possible options, YES (I would pay), NO (I wouldn’t pay) or not providing an answer (N/A). If the respondent is willing to pay the initial bid (X), a second question follows with a higher price (bid_up). If the respondent refuses to pay the first bid, the second question includes a lower price (bid_down).

The default option for those not accepting the bid is the status quo, a percutaneous coronary intervention to implant a DES without any out-of-pocket payment. When the participant is willing to pay, they are reminded that 1) if they agree to pay that amount they cannot use that money for anything else, and 2) they do not need to consider the amounts they could only afford at that time as some costs are payable via credit or are paid gradually over time.

The values of the first bid are selected randomly from a set of bids. The first and follow-up bids are shown in euro in Table 2. The bids were tested in a sample survey with 100 observations in order to check whether the range was wide enough to reflect the true WTP curve.

Table 2 Bids (€)

Finally, information was gathered on the level of fear and anxiety associated with angioplasty, age, gender, schooling, occupation, family size, net disposable income, and a few notes on participants’ attitude and understanding.

Double bounded dichotomous choice model

WTP responses were analyzed using a double bounded (DB) logit model [23]. In the empirical exercise the sequence of responses can be represented as follows. If the participant accepts to pay the first bid (q1 = Y) and the second bid (q2 = Y) the sequence is represented as YY. If the participant rejects to pay the first bid (q1 = N) and the second bid (q2 = N), the sequence is represented as NN. If the participant accepts to pay the first bid and rejects to pay the second, the sequence of responses is YN; finally, if the participant rejects to pay the first bid and accepts to pay the second bid, the sequence of responses is NY.

Participants accept the bid only if their WTP is higher, and reject it otherwise. Assuming that WTP is constant throughout the evaluation task, the sequence of responses provides an interval in which the true WTP falls (see Fig. 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

WTP intervals obtained from double-bounded questions

Assuming that WTP for participant i (WTPi) is,

$$ WT{P}_i=\mu +{\varepsilon}_i $$
(1)

where εi is an error term following a logistic distribution with a mean of 0 and a variance of \( {\tau}^2\frac{\pi^2}{3} \), being τ the scale parameter.

Under this framework, the probability of the sequence of responses is given by Hanemann et al. [23]:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\left(\mathrm{i}.\right)\to \mathrm{q}1=\mathrm{Y},\mathrm{q}2=\mathrm{Y}\\ {}=\mathit{\Pr}\left({WTP}_i\ge {bid}_{up}\right)\\ {}\begin{array}{c}=\mathit{\Pr}\left(\mu +{\varepsilon}_i\ge {bid}_{up}\right)\\ {}\begin{array}{c}=\mathit{\Pr}\left({\varepsilon}_i\ge {bid}_{up}-\mu \right)\\ {}=1-G\left(\frac{bid_{up}-\mu }{\tau}\right)\end{array}\end{array}\end{array}} $$
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\left(\mathrm{ii}.\right)\to {\mathrm{q}}_1=\mathrm{N},{\mathrm{q}}_2=\mathrm{N}\\ {}\begin{array}{c}=\mathit{\Pr}\left({WTP}_i<{bid}_{down}\right)\\ {}=\mathit{\Pr}\left(\mu +{\varepsilon}_i<{bid}_{down}\right)\\ {}\begin{array}{c}=\mathit{\Pr}\left({\varepsilon}_i<{bid}_{down}-\mu \right)\\ {}=G\left(\frac{bid_{down-}\mu }{\tau}\right)\end{array}\end{array}\end{array}} $$
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\left(\mathrm{iii}.\right)\to {\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{i}}=\mathrm{Y},{\mathrm{q}}_2=\mathrm{N}\\ {}\begin{array}{c}=\Pr \left({ bi d}_1\le WTP<{ bi d}_{up}\right)\\ {}=\Pr \left({ bi d}_1-\mu +{\upvarepsilon}_i<{ bi d}_{up}\right)\\ {}\begin{array}{c}=\Pr \left(\frac{bi{d}_1-\mu }{\tau}\le \frac{\upvarepsilon_i}{\tau }<\frac{bi{d}_{up-\mu }}{\tau}\right)\\ {}=G\left(\frac{bi{d}_{up}-\mu }{\tau}\right)-G\left(\frac{bi{d}_1-\mu }{\tau}\right)\end{array}\end{array}\end{array}} $$
$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\left(\mathrm{iv}.\right)\to {\mathrm{q}}_1=\mathrm{N},{\mathrm{q}}_2=\mathrm{Y}\\ {}=\mathit{\Pr}\left({bid}_{down}\le WTP<{bid}_1\right)\\ {}=\mathit{\Pr}\left({bid}_{down}\le \mu +{\varepsilon}_i<{bid}_1\right)\\ {}\begin{array}{c}=\mathit{\Pr}\left(\frac{bid_{down}-\mu }{\tau}\le \frac{\varepsilon_i}{\tau }<\frac{bid_1-\mu }{\tau}\right)\\ {}=G\left(\frac{bid_1-\mu }{\tau}\right)-G\left(\frac{bid_{down}-\mu }{\tau}\right)\end{array}\end{array}} $$

Estimates for \( \gamma =-\frac{1}{\tau } \) and \( \alpha =\frac{\mu }{\tau } \) are obtained by applying maximum-likelihood estimation. The log-likelihood function for this model is:

$$ \ln L=\sum \limits_{i=1}^N\left[{I}_i^{YY}\ln \left(1-G\left(\frac{b\mathrm{i}{d}_{up}-\mu }{\tau}\right)\right)\right.+ $$
$$ {I}_i^{NN}\ln {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\left(G\left(\frac{bi{d}_{down}-\mu }{\tau}\right)\right)+\\ {}\kern0.5em \end{array}} $$
$$ {I}_i^{YN}\ln \left(G\left(\frac{bi{d}_{up}-\mu }{\tau}\right)-G\left(\frac{bi{d}_1-\mu }{\tau}\right)\right) $$
$$ {I}_i^{NY}\ \left.\ln \left(G\left(\frac{bi{d}_1-\mu }{\tau}\right)-G\left(\frac{bi{d}_{down}-\mu }{\tau}\right)\right)\right] $$

And mean WTP is given by:

$$ E(WTP)=\mu =-\frac{\alpha }{\gamma } $$

In order to check for differences in WTP that could be explained by respondents´ socioeconomic differences or for the initial bid offered, we run two probit models, Model 1 to obtain coefficients for variables age, gender, years of study, employment and Model 2 that includes five dummies (k-1) corresponding to initial bids (k) that could be included in WTP estimations, as such,

$$ WTP=-\left({\beta}_0+{\beta}_1 age+{\beta}_2 gender+{\beta}_3 stud{y}_{years}+{\beta}_4 employment+{\beta}_5 bi{d}_{100}+{\beta}_6 bi{d}_{400}+{\beta}_7 bi{d}_{900}+{\beta}_8 bi{d}_{1500}+{\beta}_9 bi{d}_{3000}+{\beta}_{10} bi{d}_{6000}\right)/ bid $$

Coefficients and mean WTP were obtained in STATA.

Results

A total of 1514 participants reached the second part of the questionnaire. 114 individuals preferred treating restenosis undergoing an angioplasty over the treatment with pill and were not willing to pay for this option. These individuals did not continue with the monetary evaluation of the treatment with pill. Specified reasons for refusing to pay for the pills included the idea of the operation being more effective, and fear of side and long-term effects of the pill treatment option. Observations for nine individuals that answered “N/A” to a bid or who did not provide other relevant information were not considered. The final sample size was 1391 individuals.

Respondents showed strong support for the treatment with pills. Responses to the initial question on preferences for treating restenosis with either angioplasty or by swallowing a pill are clear: 92.5% of the respondents opt for the treatment with pills. Response distribution according to gender, level of studies and employment status are presented in Tables 3 and 4.

Table 3 Response distribution socioeconomic characteristics of survey participants (% with-in group distribution)
Table 4 Response distribution and socioeconomic characteristics of survey participants (% intra-group distribution)

WTP for a treatment will pills to avoid angioplasty

Table 5 presents coefficient estimates, t-statistics and average WTP for the complete sample. Model coefficients behave as expected; bid coefficient is negative and all coefficients are statistically significant at 1 % level. Mean WTP for the treatment with pill is €5692.87 for the sample considered. This result is higher than the findings by Greenberg et al. [32] who obtained a WTP of $1162 to reduce all risk of restenosis (estimated as a 30% reduction) and by Guertin et al., [33] who obtained a WTP of $2802 to reduce the probability of restenosis to 0. The population sample of these two studies are patients that have already undergone an angioplasty and do not include a societal perspective [34].

Table 5 DB model coefficients estimates and mean WTP estimates

Table 6 shows the results of the analysis including socioeconomic covariates (Model 1) that show higher mean WTP €6205.82. This Table also includes estimates for Model 2 with additional dummies for initial bids, WTP is €7370.59.

Table 6 Coefficients and mean WTP estimates

Mean WTP is comparable to the average cost of a percutaneous angioplasty to implant DES in Spain, in 2009, which was estimated at an average cost of €5222.65, as specified in Table 7.

Table 7 Cost of percutaneous angioplasty to implant DES (Spain, 2009. Red Española de Costes Hospitalarios (RECH), https://www.rechosp.org/)

Socioeconomic characteristics such as age, years of study and being employed are significant to explain bid acceptance and differences in WTP estimations.

Discussion

In this article two issues are introduced, why it is important to examine process utility and how such process utility might be estimated empirically. First, our results provide evidence of the existence of process utility in line with previous findings [1, 21, 35, 36]. People value avoiding angioplasty, which is a short, uncomplicated surgical procedure. Second, our CV study elicited a significant WTP for a benefit that in terms of QALYs is modest. Estimates of QALYs lost in angioplasty range from 0.0035 to 0.08 QALYs [37,38,39,40,41,42,43,44,45,46]. Ploegmakers et al., [47] find no disutility in terms of QALYs related to angioplasty. These differences in QALY’s measurements depend on different factors, such as the utility over the follow-up procedure and the length of the timeframe used in the analysis. Cohen and Baim (1995) [48] found that an intervention with initial stenting would save an additional 0.03 QALY (2 healthy weeks) with respect to standard angioplasty whereas angioplasty with stenting for restenosis would only save an additional 0.01 QALY in comparison with standard angioplasty [37]. These numbers emphasise the constraints associated with using QALY analysis to assess the utility gains associated with the avoidance of restenosis.

For our purpose, we have selected the estimation of QALY that seems representative of what our respondents are evaluating: a treatment that would avoid angioplasty. Therefore, the value of 0.0056 QALYs lost in angioplasty from Bagust et al., [38] comply with characteristics that respondents have evaluated.

This WTP estimate imply a monetary value per QALY that greatly exceed the cost per QALY thresholds established in different countries to consider health programs as beneficial to society: €25,000 in Spain [49], £25,000–£35,000/QALY in the UK [50], €20,000–€80,000 (for severe diseases)/QALY in The Netherlands [51], $60,000–$75,000 in Japan [52] and $50,000/QALY and CAD$50,000/QALY in the US and Canada, respectively [53].

Therefore, these results reflect how different methodologies for HTA may lead to different conclusions in the case in question. From the ICER perspective, the cost that would make the treatment with pills option cost-effective, using a threshold of €40,000/QALY, would be €224. However, a cost-benefit approach could support health programs even with a higher cost.

Finally, it seems that WTP methodology is able to capture outcome and process factors related to angioplasty as our WTP estimations are non significantly different for the value of the benefit individuals are evaluating. It seems that individuals are willing to pay as much as the cost of the surgery that they are avoiding. Socioeconomic characteristics such as age and years of study, and lower initial bids might explain WTP increases.

Conclusions

Findings are robust since 1) respondents have evaluated an hypothetical treatment that would avoid discomfort and/or fear of surgery and that is exactly what we have estimated in our results; 2) respondents have previously evaluated an alternative option, what they would have to go through in the case they opt for an angioplasty to implant a DES, we expect our results to be “less erratic” that in surveys were respondents are only asked to value one type of intervention, as hypothesized by Donaldson and Shackley [1].

Since both outcome and process characteristics of the intervention are clear for respondents the contribution of WTP to detect process utility will also be clear. WTP estimation is similar to the average cost of an angioplasty and coefficient of deviation is much shorter. The cost of angioplasty depends on the severity of the condition and factors such as the number of the stents implanted or days in hospital, which explains the higher dispersion in estimations. Respondents were asked to value a general, average, procedure, and their WTP is not different to average cost. WTP lower coefficient of dispersion demonstrate low variability within observations, leading us to conclude that respondents valued what they were asked to value.

The WTP approach must be considered as a genuine alternative to QALY approaches to value process utility. Notwithstanding, more research comparing the different approaches in the cases where process utility is involved are needed. Studies obtaining QALY gains and WTP estimates for process utility from the same sample could be very helpful to compare their suitability in these cases.

Our proposal is not free of critics and limitations itself. For example, it requires empirical work on willingness to pay to obtain the utility value of health. It only obtains one value for the alternative treatment to restenosis and it is difficult to compare across health states.

Availability of data and materials

All data is available upon request.

References

  1. Donaldson C, Shackley P. Does "process utility" exist? A case study of willingness to pay for laparoscopic cholecystectomy. Soc Sci Med. 1997;44(5):699–707. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0277-9536(96)00215-8.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  2. Torrance GW. Measurement of health state utilities for economic appraisal: A review. J Health Econ. 1986;5(1):1–30. https://doi.org/10.1016/0167-6296(86)90020-2.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  3. Ross WT, Simonson I. Evaluating pairs of experiences: a preference for happy endings. J Behav Decis Mak. 1991;4(4):273–82. https://doi.org/10.1002/bdm.3960040405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Loewenstein G, Prelec D. Preferences for sequences of outcomes. Psychol Rev. 1993;100(1):91–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Gafni A. Time in health: can we measure individuals´ “pure time preference”. Med Decis Mak. 1995;15(1):31–7. https://doi.org/10.1177/0272989X9501500106.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  6. Bleichrodt H, Johannesson M. The validity of QALYs. An experimental test of constant proportional trade-off and utility Independence. Med Decis Mak. 1997;17(1):21–32. https://doi.org/10.1177/0272989X9701700103.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  7. Guerrero AM, Herrero C. A semi-separable utility function for health profiles. J Health Econ. 2005;24(1):35–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Tsuchiya A, Dolan P. The QALY model and individual preferences for health states and health profiles over time: A systematic review of the literature. Med Decis Mak. 2005;25(4):460–7. https://doi.org/10.1177/0272989X05276854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Spencer A, Robinson A. Tests of utility independence when health varies over time. J Health Econ. 2007;26(5):1003–13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2007.04.002.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  10. Bewtra M, Johnson FR. Assessing patient preferences for treatment options and process of Care in Inflammatory Bowel Disease: A critical review of quantitative data. Patient-Patient-Centered Outcomes Res. 2013;6(4):241–55. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40271-013-0031-2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Matthews D, Rocchi A, Gafni A. Putting your money where your mouth is. Willingness to pay for dental gel. Pharmacoeconomics. 2002;20(4):245–55. https://doi.org/10.2165/00019053-200220040-00003.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  12. Jonas DE, Russell LB, Chou J, Pignone M. Willingness-to-pay to avoid the time spent and discomfort associated with screening colonoscopy. Health Econ. 2010;19(10):1193–211. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.1545.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  13. Lökk J, Olofsson S, Persson U. Willingness to pay for a new drug delivery in Parkinson patients. J Multidiscip Healthc. 2014;7:431–40. https://doi.org/10.2147/JMDH.S67929.

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  14. Gerard K, Mooney G. QALY league tables: handle with care. Health Econ. 1993;2(1):59–64. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.4730020108.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Mooney G. Key issues in health economics. London: Harvester Wheatsheaf; 1994.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Howard K, Salkeld G, McCaffery K, Irwig L. HPV triage testing or repeat pap smear for the management of atypical squamous cells (ASCUS) on pap smear: is there evidence of process utility? Health Econ. 2008;17(5):593–605. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.1278.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  17. Brennan VK, Dixon S. Incorporating process utility into quality adjusted life years: A systematic review of empirical studies. PharmacoEconomics. 2013;31(8):677–91. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40273-013-0066-1.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  18. Mott DJ. Incorporating quantitative patient preference data into healthcare decision making processes: is HTA falling behind? Patient-Patient-Centered Outcomes Res. 2018;11(3):249–52. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40271-018-0305-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Matza LS, Sapra SJ, Dillon JF, Kalsekar A, Davies EW, Devine MK, et al. Health state utilities associated with attributes of treatments for hepatitis C. Eur J Health Econ. 2015;16(9):1005–18. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-014-0649-6.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  20. Brouwer WBF, van Exel NJA, van den Berg B, van den Bos GAM, Koopmanschap MA. Process utility from providing informal care: the benefit of caring. Health Policy. 2005;74(1):85–99. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2004.12.008.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  21. Higgins A, Barnett J, Meads C, Singh J, Longworth L. Does convenience matter? A systematic review of convenience-based aspects of process utility. Value Health. 2014;17(8):877–87. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2014.08.2670.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  22. Arrow, K., R. Solow, P. R. Portney, E. E. Leamer, R. Radner and H. Schuman. 1993. "Report of the NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation," Federal Register, 58, 10:4601–4614.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Hanemann W, Loomis J, Kanninen B. Statistical efficiency of double-bounded dichotomous choice contingent valuation. Am J Agric Econ. 1991;73(4):1255–63. https://doi.org/10.2307/1242453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Bateman I, Burgess D, George Hutchinson W, Matthews DI. Learning design contingent valuation (LDCV): NOAA guidelines, preference learning and coherent arbitrariness. J Environ Econ Manag. 2008;55(2):127–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2007.08.003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. List J. Does market experience eliminate market anomalies? Q J Econ. 2003;118(1):41–72. https://doi.org/10.1162/00335530360535144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Ariely D. Predictably irrational. New York: Harper Collins; 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Herriges J, Shogren J. Starting point bias in dichotomous choice valuation with follow-up questioning. J Environ Econ Manag. 1996;30(1):112–31. https://doi.org/10.1006/jeem.1996.0008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Ladenburg J, Olsen S. Gender specific starting point bias in choice experiments: evidence from an empirical study. J Environ Econ Manag. 2008;56(3):275–85. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2008.01.004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Bernheim BD, Rangel A. Behavioural public economies: welfare and policy analysis with non-standard decision-makers, in behavioral economics and its applications. Peter diamond and Hannu Vartiainen (eds.): Princeton University Press; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Aviles-Blanco MV, Brey R, Araña J, Pinto-Prades JL. Emotions and scope effects in the monetary valuation of health. Eur J Health Econ. 2018;19(3):315–25. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-017-0885-7.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  31. Cookson R. Willingness to pay methods in health care: a sceptical view. Health Econ. 2003;12(11):891–4. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.847.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  32. Greenberg D, Bakhai A, Neumann PJ, Cohen DJ. Willingness to pay for avoiding coronary restenosis and repeat revascularization: results from a contingent valuation study. Health Policy. 2004;70(2):207–16. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2004.03.002.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  33. Guertin JR, Liu A, Abrahamowicz M, Cohen DJ, Ismail S, LeLorier J, et al. Willingness to pay to eliminate the risk of restenosis following percutaneous coronary intervention: a contingent valuation. Circulation. 2011;4(1):46–52. https://doi.org/10.1161/CIRCOUTCOMES.109.915421.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  34. Jönsson B. Ten arguments for a societal perspective in the economic evaluation of medical innovations. Eur J Health Econ. 2009;10(4):357–9. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-009-0173-2.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  35. Frey BS, Benz & M., Stutzer, A. Introducing procedural utility: not only what, but also how matters. J Inst Theor Econ. 2004;160(3):377–401. https://doi.org/10.1628/0932456041960560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Dolan P, Kahneman D. Interpretations of utility and their implications for the valuation of health. Economic Journal. 2008;118(525):215–34. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02110.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Hill R, Bagust A, Bakhai A, et al. Coronary artery stents: a rapid systematic review and economic evaluation. Health Technol Assess. 2004;8(35):1–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Bagust A, Grayson AD, Palmer ND, Perry RA, Walley T. Cost effectiveness of drug eluting coronary artery stenting in a UK setting: cost-utility study. Heart. 2006;92(1):68–74. https://doi.org/10.1136/hrt.2004.053850.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  39. Kaiser C, Brunner-La Rocca HP, Buser PT, et al. Incremental cost-effectiveness of drug-eluting stents compared with a third-generation bare-metal stent in a real-world setting: randomized Basel stent Kosten Effektivitats trial (BASKET). Lancet. 2005;366(9489):921–9. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0140-6736(05)67221-2.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  40. Bischof M, Briel M, Heiner CB, Nordmann A. Cost-effectiveness of drug-eluting stents in a US Medicare setting: A cost-utility analysis with 3-year clinical follow-up data. Value Health. 2009;12(5):649–56. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1524-4733.2009.00513.x.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  41. Shrive FM, Manns BJ, Galbraith PD, Knudtson ML, Ghali WA. Economic evaluation of sirolimus-eluting stents. Can Med Assoc J. 2005;172(3):345–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Cohen DJ, Taira DA, Berezin R, Cox DA, Morice MC, Stone GW, et al. Cost-effectiveness of coronary stenting in acute myocardial infarction: results from the stent primary angioplasty in myocardial infarction (stent-PAMI) trial. Circulation. 2001;104(25):3039–45. https://doi.org/10.1161/hc5001.100794.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  43. Neyt, M., van Brabandt, H., Devriese, S., et al. (2007). Drug eluting stents in Belgium: health technology assessment. Bruxelles: Belgian health care knowledge center (KCE). KCE reports 66C. (D/2007/10.273/49).

    Google Scholar 

  44. Hill RA, Boland A, Dickson R, et al. Drug-eluting stents: A systematic review and economic evaluation. Health Technol Assess. 2007;11(46):xi–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Groeneveld P, Suh JJ, Matta MA. The costs and quality of life outcomes of drug-eluting coronary stents: A systematic review. J Interv Cardiol. 2007;20(1):1–9. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-8183.2007.00214.x.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  46. Sullivan PW, Ghushchyan V. Preference-based EQ-5D index scores for chronic conditions in the United States. Med Decis Mak. 2006;26(4):410–20. https://doi.org/10.1177/0272989X06290495.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Ploegmakers MM, Viscaal AM, Finch L, Mayo NE, Brophy JM. The disutility of restenosis-the impact of repeat percutaneous coronary intervention on quality of life. Can J Cardiol. 2010;26(6):197–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0828-282x(10)70399-8.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  48. Cohen DJ, Baim DS. Coronary stenting: costly or cost-effective? J Invasive Cardiol. 1995;7(Suppl A):36A–42A.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  49. Vallejo-Torres L, García-Lorenzo B, Serrano-Aguilar P. Estimating a cost-effectiveness threshold for the Spanish NHS. Health Econ. 2018;27(4):746–61. https://doi.org/10.1002/hec.3633.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  50. Rawlins MD, Cuyler AJ. National Institute for clinical excellence and its value judgements. Br Med J. 2004;329(7459):224–7. https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.329.7459.224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Vemer P, Rutten-van Mölken MP. Largely ignored: the impact of the threshold value for a QALY on the importance of a transferability factor. Eur J Health Econ. 2011;12(5):397–404. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10198-010-0253-3.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  52. Shiroiwa T, Igarashi A, Fukuda T, Ikeda S. WTP for a QALY and health states: more money for severer health states? Cost Effective Resource Allocation. 2013;11(22):22. https://doi.org/10.1186/1478-7547-11-22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Eisenberg MJ. Drug-eluting stents: the Price is not right. Circulation. 2006;114(16):1745–54. https://doi.org/10.1161/CIRCULATIONAHA.106.646190.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Professor Raul Brey for reviewing this paper.

Funding

There has been no significant financial support for this work that could have influenced its outcome.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

The author has made substantial contributions to the conception, design of the work, the analysis and interpretation of data and have drafted the work. She approves the submitted version. She agrees to be personally accountable for her own contributions and to ensure that questions related to the accuracy or integrity of any part of the work are appropriately investigated, resolved, and the resolution documented in the literature.

Author’s information

Maria V. Aviles-Blanco is Assistant Professor at the Department of Financial Economics and Operations Management at the University of Seville.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maria V. Aviles-Blanco.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate

Not applicable.

Consent for publication

Not aplicable.

Competing interests

The author declares that she has no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/. The Creative Commons Public Domain Dedication waiver (http://creativecommons.org/publicdomain/zero/1.0/) applies to the data made available in this article, unless otherwise stated in a credit line to the data.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aviles-Blanco, M.V. Economic evaluation of process utility: elucidating preferences for a non-invasive procedure to treat restenosis. Health Econ Rev 11, 27 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13561-021-00327-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13561-021-00327-x

Keywords

JEL classification codes